Deciphering the Effects of Decentralization on Water Rights: State to Urban Inconsistencies in Bolivia, Kyle G. Webber 听听

Iceland's Environmental Saga: Motivations for Sustainable Action and Belief, Kate Gregory

Accountability for Income-Biased Representation, Patrick W. Buhr

Deciphering the Effects of Decentralization on Water Rights: State to Urban Inconsistencies in Bolivia, Kyle G. Webber

(Top of Page)

Link to Full Thesis:听

Iceland's Environmental Saga: Motivations for Sustainable Action and Belief, Kate Gregory

(Top of Page)

Link to Full Thesis:听

Accountability for Income-Biased Representation, Patrick W. Buhr

(Top of Page)

Abstract听

A growing body of research into representation has indicated that Representatives tend to favor certain constituencies when making roll-call voting decisions. These constituencies are those which are most effective at impacting the Representative鈥檚 reelection鈥攖hose who vote, communicate their preferences, are attentive to the Representative鈥檚 behavior, and contribute to their reelection. Differences on these measures tend to fall along historical听lines of discrimination听regarding race, gender, and sexual orientation. Does the same effect extend to constituents of different income levels? And, if so, are disadvantaged groups able to improve their representation or hold their Representative accountable? Numerous previous studies indicate that lower-income constituents have less policy representation than those with higher income. This study adds two novel findings to this literature. First, low-income constituents are less effective than high-income constituents at improving their representation through traditional means, such as voting or contacting their Representative directly. Second, low-income constituents are able to hold their Representatives accountable for policy decisions, but only when Representatives exhibit extreme bias. Within the margins, higher-income constituents are more effective influencing elections.听

Introduction听

鈥淒uty, gratitude, interest, ambition itself,鈥 argues James Madison in Federalist Paper No. 57, 鈥渁re the chords by which [representatives] will be bound to fidelity and sympathy with the great mass of the people鈥 (Madison 1788). Recent studies of representation, however, have discovered the outsize impact of ambition鈥攖aken to mean a reelection incentive鈥攊n shaping Representatives鈥 decisions (Mayhew 1974,听Fenno听1978,听Lijphart听1997).听听

If Representatives鈥 primary goal is to win reelection, their decisions will be largely designed to maximize their margins of victory. This may lead them to prioritize constituents with higher voting turnouts (Lijphart听1997), higher likelihoods of swing-voting (Bartels 2008), or those who are better at communicating their preferences directly or through interest groups (Miller and Stokes 1963;听Verba,听Schlozman, Brady 1995).听听

A growing body of research has indicated that these motivations tend to fall along historical patterns of discrimination. This has led to black and Latino constituents having lower rates of policy representation than white constituents (Griffin and Newman 2008). Women are less likely to have effective representation than men (Griffin,听Newman, and听Wolbrecht听2012). Homosexual听constituents are less likely to have their preferences enacted into law than heterosexual constituents (Lax, Phillips, and听Krimmel听2009).听

Does an income distinction carry the same consequences? Numerous studies have found that low-income constituents are less likely than high income constituents to have their preferences enacted into law (Gilens听2012, Flavin 2012, Rigby and Wright 2011). Few studies, however, have explicitly analyzed the mechanisms by which disadvantaged groups can improve representation, and whether these attempts are successful at holding Representatives electorally accountable.听听

This paper will seek to answer three questions:听

  1. Is income level a salient political division?听

  1. Do Representatives exhibit bias in their roll-call voting in favor of any income level?听

  1. Do mechanisms exist for disadvantaged groups to improve representation? Are听these groups听effective at holding Representatives accountable?听

By comparing policy agreement between survey respondents and Representatives, I find that there are salient political differences between the three income levels, and that Representatives have clear preferences for constituents of higher incomes. Additionally, this paper includes two novel findings. I find that disadvantaged groups are able to improve representation through voting, but do not have the same power as other groups in expanding representation听through other means. Additionally, low-income constituents have outsized influence at the extremes of policy representation, but high-income constituents continue to have the largest influence within the margins.听听

Theory and Expectations听

Numerous studies have illustrated the influence of socioeconomic factors on policy representation (Bartels 1998;听Verba,听Schlozman, and Brady 1995). These听factors fall along historical lines of discrimination, combining with unequal representation based on race (Griffin and Newman 2005), gender (Griffin, Newman, and听Wolbrecht听2012), and sexual orientation (Lax, Phillips, and听Krimmel听2009). These differences have the effect of reinforcing unequal representation, further entrenching social divisions through policy.听

The current paradigm holds that these representational inequalities are the results of differences in 鈥榲oting power鈥欌攖he different abilities of any given individual to听influence the outcome of an election (Bartels 2008). This creates a bias toward constituencies with higher rates of voter turnout (Burnham 1987)听and higher rates of swing voting (Bartels 1998). These divisions will tend to create selective incentives for Representatives to prioritize different constituencies over one another (Rosenstone听and Hansen 1997,听Verba听and听Nie听1972,听Wolfinger听and听Rosenstone听1980).听听

One of these divisions is income level, where lower turnout among lower-income constituents leads to undesirable policy (Piven听and Cloward 1988,听Gilens听2011). However, some studies have indicated that increased voting behavior has a correlation with better representation (Lijphart听1997, Fiorina 1974). This would suggest that increased voting by disadvantaged groups would鈥攖o an extent鈥攊mprove representation.听听

Likewise, Representatives are only able to agree with their constituents on policy if they are aware of their constituents鈥 preferences. Those constituents who are more effective and likely to communicate their preferences should be enjoy better representation. Numerous studies have pointed to this mechanism as another contributor to income-based representational inequality, as upper-class constituents are likely to be better informed and more effective at communicating their preferences (Miller and Stokes 1963;听Verba听2003;听Verba,听Schlozman, and Brady 1995). Increased attention to current events and increased contact with a Representative鈥檚 office has the potential to improve representation for disadvantaged groups.听听

Likewise, fundraising has become an essential aspect of modern political campaigns (Powell 2015). Representatives are forced to constantly fundraise in order to fend off challengers and prepare for an expanded and costly election cycle (Heberlig听and Larson 2014). This creates an incentive for Representatives to prioritize campaign donors, as these constituents have an听outside influence on their reelection success.听

Likewise, recent research has illustrated that many Representatives are themselves from the upper-class. This may influence the way they perceive legislation (Carnes 2013) and may shift policy in favor of the wealthy (Griffin, Newman and听Wolbrecht听2012).听

Finally, numerous studies have illustrated that constituents form opinions of their Representatives based on the roll-call votes they cast (Ansolabehere, Snyder, and Stewart 2001, Wright 1978). These constituents are then likely to hold their Representatives accountable for these votes (Erickson 1971; Canes-Wrone, Brady, and Cogan 2002). Therefore, I expect to find that Representatives with low policy agreement tend to face higher electoral penalties.听听

Methodology听

Even by听the standards of social scientists,听socioeconomic听class is a difficult concept to quantify. It includes one鈥檚 profession, tastes, speech patterns, and neighborhood. The most salient factor, however, is one鈥檚 income. According to the Pew Research Center (Brown 2016), there are substantial cultural rifts between those receiving less than 67% of the median household income (low-income), between 67% and 200% of the median household income (middle-income), and receiving 200% or above the median household income (high-income). While not encompassing of all the complexities of class, these distinctions should serve as effect proxies for the class divides between respondents.听

Independent Variable听

This paper鈥檚 method of measurement for policy agreement is the win-ratio for groups of constituents on notable pieces of legislation. In the Cooperative Congressional Election Survey (CCES),听a large-scale nationally stratified survey administered听through the website YouGov,听respondents are asked their听preference on five to twelve1听prominent pieces of legislation considered by the U.S. House of Representatives. These preferences are then compared to the actual roll call votes cast by that respondent鈥檚 Member of Congress. This produces a ratio of the Member鈥檚 policy agreement with each individual constituent.2听These ratios can then be averaged over every member of a group to produce a decimal value between 0 and 1, which can then be multiplied by 100 to produce a percentage value.听听

This method has听four primary听benefits. First, it focuses exclusively on representation from a policy perspective. Policy representation鈥攁s opposed to, for example,听securing appropriations鈥攆orces Representatives to make zero-sum decisions, with incentives changing in different contexts. Second, the CCES only considers prominent legislation. This increases both the likelihood that constituents will have formed coherent preferences, and the potential impact of the policy in question.听Third, the CCES includes between 30,000-50,000 respondents. This allows for comparisons within a single congressional district, as well as increases the statistical confidence in our findings.听Finally, creating win-ratios allows for exact comparisons across groups. This method, therefore, can be considered an accurate barometer听of how much a Representative prioritizes actually translating a听specific group鈥檚 preferences听into law.听

This measure also has its drawbacks. Representation is a multifaceted concept.听Constituents think of their Representatives as advocates, local celebrities, ombudsmen, and even personal friends (Ansolabehere听and Jones 2013). This measure of representation does not include legislation that a Representative introduces, nor how much federal funding a Representative brings to his or her district. It certainly does not听include a Representative鈥檚 success as a civic or moral leader. For the purposes of this investigation, however, the win-ratio provides the clearest听available measure of policy representation.听听

Dependent Variable听

The dependent听variable in this investigation is the electoral consequences that Representatives face for their voting decisions. Electoral outcomes are measured as the percentage change in听the margin of victory for the incumbent鈥檚 party from the previous and current elections. These values are then听subtracted from the average of all districts represented by the same party in the Congress proceeding the election. This measure is therefore able to measure relative changes in margins of victory (as opposed to a categorical variable of whether or not an incumbent was reelected), and minimizes the impact of national trends through adjusting to the national two-party vote.听

Electoral margins are听of course听subject to many variables. Much research has been done investigating how听the state of the economy (Sides and听Vavreck听2012), the quality of a challenger (Bond, Covington and Fleisher 1985), media attention (Schudson听2002), and听campaign spending by outside groups (Farrar-Myers and Skinner 2012) may affect reelection margins. By comparing Representatives against members of their own party as well as against their previous electoral performances, this measure likely encapsulates many of these exogenous variables.听听听

Descriptive Characteristics听

This investigation also includes numerous descriptive qualities, such as a respondent鈥檚 income, voting status, and attention to current events. These identifiers are self-reported through the CCES by the respondents and treated as categorical variables.听听

It is worth noting that听CCES does not have a means to verify the accuracy of these reports.听It is therefore possible听that some respondents have misreported their听status in these variables in favor of more socially acceptable answers. Any misreported descriptors, however, will decrease the magnitude of any effect, leading toward the null hypothesis.听听

There are three prominent questions addressed in this investigation: the political differences between different income levels, the preferences toward any given income a Representative may exhibit, and the mechanisms and effectiveness of disadvantaged groups at holding their Representatives accountable.听听

The first question鈥攖he political differences between incomes鈥攚ill be addressed through averages on three survey questions: a measure of general ideology, a measure of economic preferences, and a measure of social ideology. General ideology will be measured as the average place on a seven-point party identification question. Economic policy is measured by the average response to a question over whether to cut spending to decrease the national deficit. Higher scores indicate an increased preference to cut spending. Finally, social ideology will be measured by opinions on abortion, with increased scores indicating a preference toward greater legality and fewer restrictions.听听

Representatives鈥 selective decisions will be measured by taking the average win-ratio for the three income categories. This will be further broken down by party affiliation, to investigate ideological influence in policy decisions.听听

There are four mechanisms of improving representation which will be considered: voting, knowledge of current events, whether a respondent has contacted a听Representative鈥檚 office within the last year, and whether a respondent has donated to a political campaign in the last two elections. The interactions of these mechanisms for each group will be explored through a multivariate regression model. Finally, the win-ratios of all three categories will be considered against the relative change in margin of victory for the incumbent鈥檚 party. This measure will provide a final, outside measure of the relative effectiveness of each group in influencing electoral outcomes.听

Results听

My investigation proceeds in three steps. First, I seek to illustrate the differences between low-, middle-, and high-income respondents. I then investigate to what extent, if any, Representatives hold selective preferences for one group over another. Finally, I examine four common mechanisms of improving representation and test the relative impacts of changes in policy agreement on changes in electoral success.听听

Preferences听

In order for Representatives to make discriminatory decisions, and for citizens to hold Representatives accountable, respondents of different income levels must hold distinct political preferences from one another. This will be measured through three tests: general ideology, economic preferences, and social preferences.听听

Figure 1.听

Figure 1. illustrates that increases in income correspond to more conservative general听ideological preferences, while decreases in income correspond to more liberal ideological preferences. Low-income respondents were 0.2 points more liberal than middle-income respondents, and听over 0.3 points more liberal than high-income respondents.听听

Figure 2.听听

Columns represent the average response on a 100-point scale of whether cut spending or raise taxes to finance a budget deficit.听听

Likewise, Figure 2. demonstrates that low-income respondents are 4% more averse to cutting domestic spending to finance a budget deficit than were middle-income respondents, and 5% more averse than high-income respondents.听听

Figure 3.听

Average response on a four-point scale of whether to keep abortion completely legal with no restrictions, legal with some restrictions, partially legal with many restrictions, or completely illegal. Higher scores indicate preferences toward legality and lack of restrictions.听

Finally, Figure 3. indicates that, despite appearing more liberal in general and economic ideology, low- and middle-income respondents were more conservative on social issues such as abortion.听

Selective Representation听

Having established that constituents of different incomes hold divergent political beliefs, I now examine whether Representatives exhibit selective biases in how they represent different constituents.听听

Figure 4.听听

Average policy agreement for three income groups in the 110th听Congress. Error bars represent 95% confidence intervals.听

As is evident, a clear bias exists in favor of higher-income respondents. Examining Congress as a whole, high-income respondents tend to enjoy 2 points higher policy representation than low-income respondents, and 1 point higher than middle-income respondents. All results are statistically significant to a 95% confidence interval.听听

Figure 5.听

Figure 5 further examines the apparent selective representation, breaking down Representatives by party affiliation. Democrats as a whole had better policy representation, although this is to be expected from the majority party (Cox and听McCubbins听1993). While Republican听Representatives continued to prefer higher income respondents over low-income respondents, Democratic Representatives exhibited a slight preference for low- and middle-income respondents. However, the bias exhibited by Democratic Representatives was less drastic than that exhibited by Republican Representatives, potentially explaining why听low- and middle-income respondents tended to be disadvantaged in general.听

Accountability听Mechanisms听

There are four mechanisms I will examine that may mitigate the bias exhibited in the previous section: voting, attention to current events, contacting their Representative directly, or becoming involved politically.听听

Figure 6.听

Figure 6 demonstrates that there are rewards for voters of all income categories. High-income respondents received the most relative rewards, with high-income voters receiving 4 points higher representation than high-income non-voters. Low-income respondents also experienced gains, with voters receiving just over 2 points better representation than nonvoters. However, the gains received by low-income voters were not enough to reach either category for middle-income respondents, who experienced only a slight representational benefit from voting.听

Figure 7.听

Likewise, as Figure 7 indicates, low-income respondents received incremental improvements in representation for increased attention to current events, with high-awareness respondents averaging 3 points higher than respondents with no awareness. This gain, however, was not enough for low-income respondents to reach representational equity with middle- or high-income respondents of听any听awareness. These categories鈥攎iddle- and high-income鈥攄id not exhibit a consistent link between awareness and representation.听听

Figure 8听

The third mechanisms by which disadvantaged groups may influence their Representative is through contacting their Representative directly. This can be done either through calling the Representative鈥檚 office, writing a letter or signing a petition, or attending a town-hall. There were notable benefits to doing so for middle- and high-income respondents, with those having contacted an office receiving 2 point and 1.5听point improvements, respectively. For low-income respondents, however, those having contacted their Representative actually received slightly lower policy agreement.听听

Figure 9.听

The final method for disadvantaged groups to improve representation is through donating to a political campaign directly. There was some slight representational benefit to doing so for middle-income respondents, with donors receiving 1 point higher policy agreement than nondonors. For low-income and high-income respondents, however, there was no link.听听

Table 1. Multivariate Regression by Income听

Low-income听

Middle-income听

High-income听

Voting Status听

0.0241*听

(0.0134)听

0.00218听

(0.0106)听

0.0284听

(0.022)听

Current Events听

0.007听

(0.0119)听

0.001861听

(0.0084)听

0.00378听

(0.0156)听

Contact with Office听

0.00198听

(0.009)听

0.0205***听

(0.0053)听

0.01866**听

(0.00655)听

Donation听

-0.005听

(0.0105)听

0.0012听

(0.0054)听

0.0053听

(0.0066)听

Constant听

0.5023***听

(0.0284)听

0.5403听

(0.0226)听

0.4922***听

(0.0474)听

Multivariate Regression model between policy agreement and voting status, current events awareness, contact with office and donations. *p<0.1, **p<0.01, ***p<.0.001听

As Table 1 demonstrates, the only statistically significant method of improving representation for low-income respondents is through increased voting. However, the gains from voting continue to be highest for high-income constituents.听Low-income respondents have the highest rewards for increased media attention, but this change is insignificant. Middle- and high-income respondents have very high correlations between representation and contact with their representative鈥檚 office鈥攖here was little correlation for low-income respondents. Finally, no income level received notable correlations between political donations and representation.听

Political Consequences听

Finally, I examine whether Representatives face electoral consequences for differences in their roll-call voting.听听

Figure 10 indicates that, for all income levels, there is a positive relationship between policy agreement and relative change in incumbent party鈥檚 vote margin.听听

There are two striking observations from this data. First, low-income constituents have outsized impacts on electoral consequences at the extremes of representation, with Representatives agreeing with low-income constituents above 0.85 receiving disproportionate benefits, and Representatives agreeing with low-income constituents below听0.3 receiving disproportionate costs.听听

Within the margins, however, all three income levels appear to advance semi-linearly.3听High income respondents have the highest slope, followed by middle-income respondents, and with low-income respondents with the lowest slope.听听

This indicates that, within the margins of 0.4 and 0.8, Representatives receive a higher marginal vote share for representing constituents of increased incomes. Low-income respondents, therefore, are able to hold their Representatives accountable, but only outside the normal range of representation.听听

Conclusion听

The purpose of this investigation was to investigate the representational differences between constituents of different incomes, how constituents can improve their representation, and whether constituents hold Representatives accountable for differences in policy agreement.听听

This study was not a perfect measure of accountability. The Congresses examined both included heavy Democratic majorities,听and did not examine nonelection years. Both of these factors would have worked in favor of low-income policy agreement, possibly diminishing the significance of any findings.听听

Likewise, each piece of legislation was treated as equal. There was no measure for the issue鈥檚 salience between groups, the media attention paid toward the bills, or whether the legislation was ultimately enacted.听听

Finally, both elections examined featured huge partisan swings. These swings had many exogenous influences, such as the Global Financial Crisis or the Tea Party movement, which were not accounted for. Likewise, district characteristics were not accounted for, nor were challenger quality and听differences in turnout between groups.听

There were several prominent findings.听As many scholars have noted, large representational gaps exist between constituents of different incomes. These effects are compounded by party, with Democrats agreeing more with low-income constituents, and Republicans agreeing with high-income constituents.听听

Low-income constituents are able to improve their representation through voting, but are ineffective at improving agreement through other means.听听

Finally, low-income respondents have a disproportionate effect on electoral outcomes at the margins, yielding huge rewards for extremely high representation and huge punishments for extremely low representation. Within, the margins, however, higher-income constituents are still more effective at holding their听Representatives accountable.听听

Both of these novel findings hold significant normative value. How can disadvantaged groups improve representation if the mechanisms do not听work equally for different groups? How can these groups hold their Representatives accountable if their influence is only effective at the margins? Are听these findings consistent with the principles of democracy, or in the intent behind a republican form of government?听

If, as Martin Luther King famously stated, 鈥渢he moral arc of the universe is long, but it bends toward justice,鈥 those groups disadvantaged by biases in representation must be capable of altering the system. As this investigation demonstrates, that capacity is rarely realized.听听

References听

Ansolabehere, Stephen, James M. Snyder, and Charles Stewart. "Candidate Positioning in U.S. House Elections."鈥疉merican Journal of Political Science鈥45, no. 1 (2001): 136.听听

Bartels, Larry M. "Electoral Continuity and Change, 1868鈥1996."鈥疎lectoral Studies17, no. 3 (1998): 301-26.听听

Bartels, Larry M.鈥疷nequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2008.听

Bond, Jon R., Cary Covington, and Richard Fleisher. "Explaining Challenger Quality in Congressional Elections."鈥疶he Journal of Politics鈥47, no. 2 (1985): 510-29.听听

Brown, Anna. "What Americans Say It Takes to Be Middle Class." Pew Research Center RSS. 2016. Accessed April 27, 2016. .听

Burnham, Walter Dean. "Elections as Democratic Institutions."鈥疭ociety鈥24, no. 4 (1987): 38-48. doi:10.1007/bf02695792.听

Canes-Wrone,听Brandice, David W. Brady, and John F. Cogan. "Out of Step, Out of Office: Electoral Accountability and House Members' Voting."鈥疉m. Pol. Sci. Rev. American Political Science Review鈥96, no. 01 (2002). doi:10.1017/s0003055402004276.听

Carnes, Nicholas.鈥疻hite-collar Government: The Hidden Role of Class in Economic Policy Making.听

Cox, Gary W., and Mathew D.听McCubbins.鈥疞egislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993.听

Enns, Peter, and Christopher听Wlezien.鈥疻ho Gets Represented?鈥疦ew York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2011.听

Erickson, Robert S. "The Electoral Impact of Congressional Roll Call Voting."鈥疶he American Political Science Review鈥65, no. 4 (1971): 1018.听听

Farrar-Myers, Victoria A., and Richard Skinner. "Super听Pacs听and the 2012 Elections."鈥疭SRN Electronic Journal SSRN Journal.听听

Fenno, Richard F.鈥疕ome Style: House Members in Their Districts. Boston: Little, Brown, 1978.听

Fiorina, Morris P.鈥疪epresentatives, Roll Calls, and Constituencies. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1974.听

Flavin, Patrick. "Does Higher Voter Turnout among the Poor Lead to More Equal Policy Representation?"鈥疶he Social Science Journal鈥49, no. 4 (2012): 405-12.听

Gilens, Martin.鈥疉ffluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press, 2012.听

Griffin, John David, and Brian Newman.鈥疢inority Report: Evaluating Political Equality in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2008.听

Griffin, John D., Brian Newman, and Christina听Wolbrecht. "A Gender Gap in Policy Representation in the U.S. Congress?"鈥疞egislative Studies Quarterly鈥37, no. 1 (2012): 35-66.听

Heberlig, Eric S., and Bruce A. Larson. "U.S. House Incumbent Fundraising and Spending in a Post- Citizens United and Post- McCutcheon World."鈥疨olitical Science Quarterly鈥129, no. 4 (2014): 613-42.听听

Lax, Jeffrey R., and Justin H. Phillips. "Gay Rights in the States: Public Opinion and Policy Responsiveness."鈥疉m Polit Sci听Rev American Political Science Review103, no. 03 (2009): 367.听

Lijphart,听Arend.鈥疶hinking about Democracy: Power Sharing and Majority Rule in Theory and Practice. London: Routledge, 2008.听

Mayhew, David R.鈥疌ongress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1974.听

Miller, Warren E., and Donald E. Stokes. "Constituency Influence in Congress."Am Polit Sci Rev American Political Science Review鈥57, no. 01 (1963): 45-56.听

Munro, Gary. "Who Votes? Raymond E.听Wolfinger听and Steven听Rosenstone听New Haven: Yale University Press, 1980, Pp. X, 158."鈥疌an J Pol Sci Canadian Journal of Political Science鈥14, no. 03 (1981): 672.听

Polsby, Nelson W., Frances Fox听Piven, and Richard A. Cloward. "Why Americans Don't Vote."鈥疌ontemporary Sociology鈥17, no. 6 (1988): 784.听听

Rosenstone, Steven J., John Mark Hansen, and Donald R. Kinder. "Measuring Change in Personal Economic Well-Being."鈥疨ublic Opinion Quarterly鈥50, no. 2 (1986): 176.听

Schickler, Eric, and Frances E. Lee.鈥疶he Oxford Handbook of the American Congress. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011.听

Schudson, Michael. "The Business of Media: Corporate Media and the Public Interest."鈥疶he Information Society鈥18, no. 4 (2002): 307-08.听

Sides, John, and Lynn听Vavreck.鈥疶he Gamble: Choice and Chance in the 2012 Presidential Election.听

Verba, Sidney, and Norman H.听Nie.鈥疨articipation in America: Political Democracy and Social Equality. New York: Harper & Row, 1972.听

Verba, Sidney, Kay Lehman听Schlozman, and Henry E. Brady.鈥疺oice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in American Politics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1995.听